A Defense of Disclosure (Including Third-Party Disclosure) by Jacob Nails

1151000_714844848531977_513931540_n

A Defense of Disclosure (Including Third-Party Disclosure) by Jacob Nails

With the revival of LDLeaks, the debate about disclosure – in particular forced disclosure – has also experienced a partial revival. I’ve seen a number of discussions crop up in the past few weeks on Facebook and in private. The number of teams that disclose has slowly but steadily increased over the past few years. However, there has not been a sustained public discussion of disclosure in quite some time. I’ve been asked to write on the issue, and I agree that it is a good discussion to have, so this article will lay out the arguments I find persuasive for public case disclosure, including involuntary case disclosure by third parties.

For those unfamiliar with the concept, disclosure refers to the norm of posting the taglines and citations of one’s cases on the NDCA wiki, which as of this season has moved to http://hsld.debatecoaches.org. Disclosure started as a norm in policy debate and gradually made its way over to Lincoln Douglas, starting in the ’08-’09 season. Before Glenbrooks ’11, LDLeaks (http://ldleaks.wikispaces.com/) was created as a place where debaters could publicly post flows. The site fell into relative disuse last year but was revived at the beginning of the ’13-’14 season, reigniting some of the old discussions over disclosure. Disclosure’s proponents tout increased transparency, while detractors claim that it stifles creativity.

I fall squarely on the side of disclosure. I find that the largest advantage of widespread disclosure is the educational value it provides. First, disclosure streamlines research. Rather than every team and every lone wolf researching completely in the dark, the wiki provides a public body of knowledge that everyone can contribute to and build off of. Students can look through the different studies on the topic and choose the best ones on an informed basis without the prohibitively large burden of personally surveying all of the literature. The best arguments are identified and replicated, which is a natural result of an open marketplace of ideas. Quality of evidence increases across the board.

In theory, the increased quality of information could trade off with quantity. If debaters could just look to the wiki for evidence, it might remove the competitive incentive to do one’s own research. Empirically, however, the opposite has been true. In fact, a second advantage of disclosure is that it motivates research. Debaters cannot expect to make it a whole topic with the same stock AC – that is, unless they are continually updating and frontlining it. Likewise, debaters with access to their opponents’ cases can do more targeted and specific research. Students can go to a new level of depth, researching not just the pros and cons of the topic but the specific authors, arguments, and adovcacies employed by other debaters. The incentive to cut author-specific indicts is low if there’s little guarantee that the author will ever be cited in a round but high if one knows that specific schools are using that author in rounds. In this way, disclosure increases incentive to research by altering a student’s cost-benefit analysis so that the time spent researching is more valuable, i.e. more likely to produce useful evidence because it is more directed. In any case, if publicly accessible evidence jeopardized research, backfiles and briefs would have done LD in a long time ago.

Lastly, and to my mind most significantly, disclosure weeds out anti-educational arguments. I have in mind the sort of theory spikes and underdeveloped analytics whose strategic value comes only from the fact that the time to think of and enunciate responses to them takes longer than the time spent making the arguments themselves. If these arguments were made on a level playing field where each side had equal time to craft answers, they would seldom win rounds, which is a testimony to the real world applicability (or lack thereof) of such strategies. A model in which arguments have to withstand close scrutiny to win rounds creates incentive to find the best arguments on the topic rather than the shadiest. Having transitioned from LD to policy where disclosure is more universal, I can say that debates are more substantive, developed, and responsive when both sides know what they’re getting into prior to the round.

The educational benefits of disclosure alone aren’t likely to convince the fairness-outweighs-education crowd, but I’ve learned over the course of many theory debates that most of that crowd has a very warped and confusing conception of fairness. Debaters who produce better research are more deserving of a win. Debaters who can make smart arguments and defend them from criticism should win out over debaters who hide behind obfuscation. That so many rounds these days are resolved on frivolous theory and dropped, single-sentence blips suggests that wins are not going to the “better debaters” in any meaningful sense of the term. The structure of LD in the status quo doesn’t incentivize better debating.

Then there’s the issue of small schools. 75% of debaters in quarterfinals of the TOC and the same percent in semifinals practiced disclosure. 25% didn’t, but I would figure that upwards of 90% of debaters at the TOC knew what cases those two debaters were reading anyway. It’s not the big schools that they succeeded in hiding their cases from; it was the small schools with few connections. To quote Mike Bietz

“[B]ig teams already get many, many more flows than the smaller teams just because they have more debaters, more judges and more coaches. Open disclosure gives everyone access to the same information. Additionally, it helps the ‘little guy’ even more because for many of these debaters, the option of going to a lot of tournaments isn’t available. Open case disclosure gives them the ability to see what other teams are running prior to showing up to the tournament. Thus, there is an added benefit of equalizing not only information at a tournament, but also equalizing (to some degree) the playing-field for people who do not have the resources to travel as much.”1

Some have claimed that disclosure stifles creativity. I think it is important to draw the line between creativity and inanity. Creative arguments no less than others should be able to stand up to close scrutiny, and if the “creative” argument in question would be unwinnable if one’s opponent knew about it beforehand, then I think “creative” here is little more than a pseudonym for “cheap-shot.” There is still room for true creativity alongside disclosure. Debaters are constantly breaking new positions and searching for arguments that haven’t been extensively researched by opponents.  I have trouble thinking of a case that I would say was valuably creative and innovational and yet so weak that disclosure would weed it out.

So, disclosure is all right and good, but that doesn’t settle whether it should be voluntary. Should your opponent be able to disclose your case to other debaters without your consent? The universal consensus among LDers is YES. In my 6 years in the Lincoln Douglas debate community, I have yet to meet a single debater who refused to share their flow of an opponent’s case with teammates, friends, and usually even acquaintances. Even on local circuits where voluntary case disclosure is unheard-of, flow-sharing occurs regularly and uncontroversially.

Advancements in technology have allowed the practice of involuntary third-party disclosure to become more widespread than ever. Here on the East coast, it is relatively easy to find out what cases are being run at California tournaments within minutes of their being broken, via Facebook, GChat, or text message. Judicious networking is all it takes to get flows of most debaters on the natural circuit. Even with these developments, there has not been any backlash. No one has called for a norm against behind-closed-doors sharing of flows electronically.

Making that same process public seems like a relatively innocuous next step. Everyone who travels regularly, along with anyone with connections, already has or could easily acquire flows from most schools. LDLeaks takes the flow-sharing process one step further by democratizing information so that everyone can access it, not just those with the right backchannels. Instead of sharing flows with teammates, debaters now share flows with the whole community.

LDLeaks has received some criticism, including claims that it violates intellectual property law2 (a myth which I believe has been totally debunked by now), but “disclosure bad” does not seem like a valid response. The alternative to LDLeaks is not non-disclosure of flows. It is disclosure only in elite circles and among people who can afford to travel. Completely eliminating third-party flow-sharing seems neither possible nor desirable. Even if that is the ideal, complete disclosure seems like the next-best feasible option. The middle ground of dominance by the in-group is the worst of both worlds.

1. Bietz, Mike. “The Case for Public Case Disclosure.” NFL Rostrum, Vol. 84, Issue 9. May 2010. <https://nationalforensicleague.org/DownloadHandler.ashx?File=/userdocs/publications/05-2010%20Complete%20Rostrum.pdf>

2. The Case Against LD Leaks: The Relevance of Intellectual Property Law. Wednesday, February 8th, 2012.

<http://nsdupdate.com/2012/the-case-against-ld-leaks-the-relevance-of-intellectual-property-law/>

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

  • Pingback: Premier Debate Today – Disclosure Enhances Creativity – Bob Overing()

  • Pingback: Premier Debate Today – Is disclosure theory different?()

  • Anonymous

    I am going to start off by saying that I think post-topic disclosure and disclosing at least one aff and neg case on the wiki (at least for people who are nationally competitive) is a good thing since it will help novices get an idea for basic aff and neg ground, case structure, and topic lit. However, I don’t think that you should be required to disclose more than that or during the topic.

    The biggest problem that I have with mandatory disclosure is that it screws small schools over. Mandatory disclosure encourages either larger schools or people who have more time to prep out all the positions. Large schools have more resources, which means they have a greater advantage in creating huge dumps and prep outs. Meanwhile, the lone wolf debater often doesn’t the ability to do all the prep if they come from a program with no support, resources, or access to higher research. This puts the larger schools at a structural advantage, making it much easier for
    them to win rounds. I don’t find Bietz’s arguments particularly compelling
    since even if large schools have a larger reach in the first place, they don’t
    have the infinite reach that they have if everyone disclosed everything. They
    may have five additional flows from the tournaments they attended; however,
    they won’t have access to cases that people read across the country at
    tournaments that aren’t bids unless disclosure was practiced. Also, I think
    that disclosing one case still helps the ‘little guy’ prep. However, the
    argument that it helps the little guy since they can look assumes that they
    actually have the time and resources to prep out the arguments in the first
    place. And, the argument from Bietz that there will be equal time to craft
    answers is cancelled out by the huge advantage that big schools have. Even if
    there is equal time, big schools have more resources to make better prep outs.

    Furthermore, I believe that disclosure leads to a decrease in creativity. Jacob argues that there is a difference between inanity and creativity. And, forced disclosure doesn’t prevent wins on blippy arguments; if anything it guarantees more blippy arguments because debaters and coaches will work to write a dump of responses rather than specific nuanced ones. The argument that you should have to stand up to close scrutiny is not responsive as I agree that your arguments should be good and you should be able to defend them; however, what disclosure does is normalize smart arguments that you could have spent a lot of time crafting,
    meaning that other’s who didn’t do as much as you had to can simply copy your
    work.

    Jacob also said that disclosure would weed out non-educational arguments; however, I don’t believe this to be true since it doesn’t seem like most people disclose all the theory spikes in their AC’s on the wiki. Most just disclose tags and
    author names. Also, if your opponent’s argument is shady, it shouldn’t take you
    long to deal with it (if it truly is stupid) by simply making no warrant
    arguments. I don’t think that you deserve to win the round if you can’t make
    responses to shady arguments. I believe that better responses to arguments on
    the fly as opposed to reading prep is the greater indication of who the better
    debater actually is.

    Finally,
    Jacob argued that disclosure increases education; however, disclosing one case
    seems like a better alternative as then people get a general feel for stock
    AC’s on the topic, while still having to come up with arguments on their own.
    Additionally, under a system of non-disclosure, it doesn’t seem to deter
    everyone from writing new AC’s in the first place. Plus, it seems that you
    would be able to cut author specific indicts by being at tournaments in the
    first place. And there’s really no reason as to why author specific indicts are
    good. If anything, author specific indicts usually devolve into ad hominem
    attacks.

    Now, on the case of LD Leaks. The arguments for why mandatory disclosure
    is bad would respond to the arguments for why posting cases on line is bad for
    the reasons I listed above. Additionally, posting someone’s case for the entire
    debate community to see without their consent seems like something that we should
    try to prevent. Although the same flow may be shared with others, it isn’t to
    the extent of allowing everyone to see it, and I don’t believe that flows are
    actually traded among elite groups of people across the country after whatever debate tournament they were at ended.

    • Jacob Nails

      I’ll keep my response to a few short thoughts because I’ve got an exam to study for.

      1. I can’t see any incentive for debaters to post their best cases under “single case disclosure.” Expect to see 100 stock ACs on the wiki which don’t at all reflect the debaters’ real strategies. If anything, SCD would be a larger burden on small schools that have only one case to disclose.

      2. Disclosing theory spikes (especially the interps) is a practice which I would not be opposed to.

      3. Non-disclosure obviously does not lead to more “specific nuanced” responses (why would this be the case?). Analytic dumps exist largely because debaters don’t have time to cut and organize evidenced responses prior to the debate. Look at policy rounds and rounds between disclosed LDers, both of which tend to have fewer analytic dumps.

      4. Your last sentence severely underestimates the extent of flowsharing. You’re right earlier-on in the post when you say elite debaters have far more resources. One of those is networks.The cost of non-disclosure for any “in” debater is that they have to do an hour or two of networking to get all the info that would be on the wiki. The cost to outgroup debaters without connections is that they don’t get that info at all.

  • UTIL.DB8R

    I agree with the article, i wont go further because i would repeat the same argument you made. One question though: what should one do if debaters have deleted their cites from tournaments with mandatory disclosure?

    • JacobN1

      Simple, if you see someone who tried to circumvent Greenhill policy by deleting their case, post it on LD Leaks. If you don’t know how to access prior revisions, message me or someone involved in LD Leaks. The cases are always accessible, even if they aren’t visible.